An economic model of the life-cycle research productivity of scientists

Author:

Diamond A. M.

Publisher

Springer Science and Business Media LLC

Subject

Library and Information Sciences,Computer Science Applications,General Social Sciences

Reference11 articles.

1. H. LEHMAN,Age and Achievement, Oxford University Press, London, 1953, pp. 3–21 and 308–323 (on mathematicians see especially pp. 8 and 311).

2. F. CAJORI,A History of Mathematics, 2nd ed., the Macmillan Co., New York, 1922.

3. LEHMAN, pp. 328–329.

4. W. DENNIS, Age and Achievement: A Critique,Journal of Gerontology, 11 No. 3, (July 1956) 331–333; Age and Productivity among Scientists,Science, 123 (April 27, 1956) 724–725; The Age Decrement in Outstanding Scientific Contributions: Fact or Artifact?,The American Psychologist, 13, (Aug. 1958) 457–460; Creative Productivity between the Ages of 20 and 80 Years,Journal of Gerontology. 21, No. 1, (Jan. 1966) 1–8; N. STERN, Age and Achievement in Mathematics: A Case-Study in the Sociology of Science,Social Studies of Science, 8 (1978) 127–140; H. ZUCKERMAN, Appendix E: Age-Specific Annual Rates of Productivity of Laureates and Matched Sample of Scientists Who Survived to Each Age, inScientific Elite. The Free Press, New York 1977, pp. 301–302; S. COLE, Age and Scientific Performance,American Journal of Sociology. 84 No. 4, (Jan. 1979) 958–977; I originally thought that a third current position, distinct from those ofLehman andCole, wasPrice's version of the ‘contagion’ model (D. de SOLLA PRICE, A General Theory of Bibliometric and Other Cumulative Advantage Processes,Journal of the American Society for Information Science (Sept.–Oct. (1976) 292–306.) I interpretedPrice's model as implying that for those who ‘caught on’ productivity would increase with age (see pp. 303–304 of above). ButPrice claims that I misinterpreted him and that in fact he agrees withCole: “My own feeling is that productivity in quantity and quality are approximately constant with age though of course productivity must rise from zero to its level during the first few years of scholarly activity and towards the end of life there may well be, in some but not all cases, a tendency to make a slight decline.” (letter, June 23, 1980). See also: D. de SOLLA PRICE, The Productivity of Research Scientists, inYearbook of Science and the Future 1975, Encyclopedia Britannica. 1974. An application ofPrice's contagion model that, from the title, would seem to bear on the age/productivity issue is: Y. WEISS, L. LILLARD, Output Variability. Academic Labor Contracts and Waiting Time for Promotion, in R. G. EHRENBERG, Ed.,Research in Labor Economics 5, (1982) 157–188.Weiss andLillard, however, want to insulate their model from any prima facie implications it might have for the issue: “For the purpose of our analysis it isnot necessary to assume that output is measurable. One can think of abstract andunobserved ‘promotion capital’ which is related, but not necessarily identical to the number of published papers. One can maintain the specific distribution implications of the model for time to promotion without necessarily maintaining the specific distributional implications for papers production” (p. 172, italics in original). DespitePrice's concurrence withCole et al., the current consensus about age/productivity profiles is not total. For a sample of 20 past presidents of the American Economic Association,Eagly found that number of articles peaked at 6 per year at age 47 and declined to about 2 per year at age 67 (R. EAGLY, Contemporary Profile of Conventional Economists,History of Political Economy, 6, No. 1, (1974) 88). For a sample of 5079 scientists,Bayer andDutton compare 6 functional forms of the quantity/age relation of find out which one provides the ‘best fit’. Since they require that all the betas be significant for the model that ‘fits best’, they rule out from the start the possibility that productivity is constant with age (in which case, the constant, but none of the betas would be significant). Of the remaining 6 functional forms, they find that a 4th degree polynomial of age (which they call the spurt-obsolescence function) provides the best fit (A. E. BAYER, J. E. DUTTON, Career Age and Research-Professional Activities of Academic Scientists,Journal of Higher Education, 48, No. 3, (May/June, 1977), pp. 259–282).

5. Noting correctly that “longitudinal data are superior to cross-sectional data in measuring the effects of age on scientific productivity,” (p. 964)Cole uses longitudinal data for a sample of 497 mathematicians who received their Ph. D.'s between 1947 and 1950. For five year periods between 1950 and 1975,Cole finds that mean citations (in 1975) to articles written in each period varied only slightly around one citation per article (p. 695). From this,Cole concludes that quality of output does not decline with age.Cole's method can be criticized on several grounds. Perhaps the most important of these is that in the early periods the sample includes work by low-quality mathematicians who later stop publishing. Since their work diminishes the group mean in the early periods and since the group mean remains constant over all periods, it follows that the mean quality of work for those mathematicians who continue to publish must decline with age.

Cited by 87 articles. 订阅此论文施引文献 订阅此论文施引文献,注册后可以免费订阅5篇论文的施引文献,订阅后可以查看论文全部施引文献

同舟云学术

1.学者识别学者识别

2.学术分析学术分析

3.人才评估人才评估

"同舟云学术"是以全球学者为主线,采集、加工和组织学术论文而形成的新型学术文献查询和分析系统,可以对全球学者进行文献检索和人才价值评估。用户可以通过关注某些学科领域的顶尖人物而持续追踪该领域的学科进展和研究前沿。经过近期的数据扩容,当前同舟云学术共收录了国内外主流学术期刊6万余种,收集的期刊论文及会议论文总量共计约1.5亿篇,并以每天添加12000余篇中外论文的速度递增。我们也可以为用户提供个性化、定制化的学者数据。欢迎来电咨询!咨询电话:010-8811{复制后删除}0370

www.globalauthorid.com

TOP

Copyright © 2019-2024 北京同舟云网络信息技术有限公司
京公网安备11010802033243号  京ICP备18003416号-3